Books
in black and white
Main menu
Share a book About us Home
Books
Biology Business Chemistry Computers Culture Economics Fiction Games Guide History Management Mathematical Medicine Mental Fitnes Physics Psychology Scince Sport Technics
Ads

Valuation Measuring and managing the value ofpanies - Koller T.

Koller T., Murrin J. Valuation Measuring and managing the value ofpanies - Wiley & sons , 2000. - 508 p.
ISBN 0-471-36190-9
Download (direct link): valuationmeasuringandmanaging2000.pdf
Previous << 1 .. 56 57 58 59 60 61 < 62 > 63 64 65 66 67 68 .. 197 >> Next

This alternative calculation generates the same value for economic profit:
Economic profit = S100 - ($1,000 x 8%)
This approach shows that economic profit is similar in concept to accounting net income, but it explicitly charges a company for all its capital, not just the interest on its debt.
A simple example will illustrate how economic profit can be used for valuations. Assume that Company C from above invested $1,000 in working capital and fixed assets at the beginning of period 1. Each year after that it earns $100 of NOPLAT (a 10 percent ROIC). Its net investment is zero, so its free cash flow is also $100. Company C's economic profit is $20 a year as calculated above.
The economic profit approach says that the value of a company equals the amount of capital invested plus a premium or discount equal to the present value of its projected economic profit:
Value = Invested capital + Present value of projected economic profil
The logic behind this is straightforward. If a company earned exactly its WACC every period, then the discounted value of its projected free cash flow should exactly equal its invested capital. The company is worth exactly what was originally invested. A company is worth more or less than its invested capital only to the extent that it earns more or less than its WACC. Therefore, the premium or discount relative to invested capital must equal the present value of the company's future economic profit.
Company C earns $20 a year more than investors demand (its economic profit). So the value of company C should equal $1,000 (its invested capital at the time of the valuation) plus the present value of its economic profit. In this case since economic profit remains forever at $20 a year, we can use a perpetuity formula to calculate the present value of its economic profit.
Page 145
Present value of economic profit =
Company C's value is $1,250. If you were to discount company C's free cash flow you would also end up with a value for company C of $1,250. Company C's projected free cash flow is $100 a year.
Present value of PO-
SH*
’ 8%
= 51,250
Exhibits 8.11 and 8.12 show the economic profit and economic profit valuation of Hershey Foods. In 1998, Hershey generated economic profit of $293 million. In other words, Hershey made $293 million of operating profit more than required by investors based on the returns available from alternative investments. Note that the economic profit value of Hershey exactly equals the discounted free cash flow value that we calculated earlier in this chapter. Furthermore, as would be expected, the value of operations, $10.2 billion, exceeds the amount of invested capital (at the end of 1998) of $1.8 billion. In present value terms, Hershey has created $8.4 billion of value ($10.2 billion less $1.8 billion).
Exhibit 8.11 Hershey Foods—Economic Profit Calculation
Forecast Forecast Forecast
$ million 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Return on invested capital 24.3% 23.0% 23.0% 22.7% 22.6%
WACC 8.3% 7.5^0 7.5% 7.5% 7.5%
Spread 16.0% 15.5% 15.5% 15.2% 15.1%
Invested capital (beginning of year) 1,815 1,885 1,830 1,919 2,005
Economic profit 291 293 283 292 304
NOPLAT 442 434 420 436 454
Capital charge (151) (141) (137) (144) (150)
Economic profit 291 293 283 292 304
Page 146
Exhibit 8.12 Hershey Foods—Economic Profit Valuation Summary
/-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------\
Year Economic Discount factor Present value of
profit (7.5%) economic profit
{S million) ($ million1)
1999 283 0.930 263
2000 292 0.865 252
2001 304 0.805 245
2002 316 0.749 237
2003 329 0.697 li‘3
2004 343 0.648 222
2005 357 0.603 215
2006 372 0.561 209
2007 387 0 522 202
2008 403 0.485 1%
Continuing value 11,858 0.485 5,754
Present value of economic profit 8,024
Invested capital (beginning of year) 1,830
9,854
Mid-year adjustment factor 1.037
Value of operations 10,217
Value of non-operating investments 450
Total enterprise value 10,667
Less: Value of debt 1,282
Equity value 9,385
1 Except per share.
V, J
The Adjusted Present Value (APV) Model
The adjusted present value (APV) model is similar to the enterprise DCF model. As with enterprise DCF, the APV model discounts free cash flows to estimate the value of operations, and ultimately the enterprise value, once non-operating assets are added. From this enterprise value, the value of debt is deducted to arrive at an equity value. The difference is that the APV model separates the value of operations into two components: the value of operations as if the company were entirely equity-financed and the value of the tax benefit arising from debt financing.2
This valuation model reflects the conclusions from the Modigliani-Miller propositions on capital structure developed in the late 1950s and early 1960s. The MM propositions showed that in a world with no taxes, the enterprise value of a company (the sum of its debt plus equity) is independent of capital structure (or the amount of debt relative to equity). The intuitive logic here is that the value of a company should not be affected by how
Previous << 1 .. 56 57 58 59 60 61 < 62 > 63 64 65 66 67 68 .. 197 >> Next